Книжная полка Сохранить
Размер шрифта:
А
А
А
|  Шрифт:
Arial
Times
|  Интервал:
Стандартный
Средний
Большой
|  Цвет сайта:
Ц
Ц
Ц
Ц
Ц

Review of Business and Economics Studies, 2016, том 4, № 1

Покупка
Основная коллекция
Артикул: 705317.0001.99
Review of Business and Economics Studies, 2016, том 4, № 1: Журнал - :, 2016. - 94 с.: ISBN. - Текст : электронный. - URL: https://znanium.com/catalog/product/1014590 (дата обращения: 28.04.2024). – Режим доступа: по подписке.
Фрагмент текстового слоя документа размещен для индексирующих роботов. Для полноценной работы с документом, пожалуйста, перейдите в ридер.
Review of 
Business and
Economics 
Studies

EDITOR-IN-CHIEF
Prof. Alexander Ilyinsky
Dean, International Finance Faculty, 
Financial University, Moscow, Russia
ailyinsky@fa.ru 

EXECUTIVE EDITOR
Dr. Zbigniew Mierzwa

EDITORIAL BOARD

Dr. Mark Aleksanyan
Adam Smith Business School, 
The Business School, University 
of Glasgow, UK

Prof. Edoardo Croci
Research Director, IEFE Centre for 
Research on Energy and Environmental 
Economics and Policy, Università 
Bocconi, Italy

Prof. Moorad Choudhry
Dept.of Mathematical Sciences, Brunel 
University, UK

Prof. David Dickinson 
Department of Economics, Birmingham 
Business School, University of 
Birmingham, UK

Prof. Chien-Te Fan
Institute of Law for Science and 
Technology, National Tsing Hua 
University, Taiwan

Prof. Wing M. Fok
Director, Asia Business Studies, College 
of Business, Loyola University New 
Orleans, USA

Prof. Konstantin P. Gluschenko
Faculty of Economics, Novosibirsk State 
University, Russia

Prof. George E. Halkos
Associate Editor in Environment and 
Development Economics, Cambridge 
University Press; Director of Operations 
Research Laboratory, University of 
Thessaly, Greece

Dr. Christopher A. Hartwell
President, CASE — Center for Social and 
Economic Research, Warsaw, Poland

Prof. S. Jaimungal
Associate Chair of Graduate 
Studies, Dept. Statistical Sciences 
& Mathematical Finance Program, 
University of Toronto, Canada

Prof. Bartlomiej Kaminski
University of Maryland, USA; 

Rzeszow University of Information 
Technology and Management, 
Poland

Prof. Vladimir Kvint 
Chair of Financial Strategy, Moscow 
School of Economics, Moscow State 
University, Russia

Prof. Alexander Melnikov 
Department of Mathematical and 
Statistical Sciences, University of 
Alberta, Canada

Prof. George Kleiner
Deputy Director, Central Economics and 
Mathematics Institute, Russian Academy 
of Sciences, Russia

Prof. Kwok Kwong
Director, Asian Pacifi c Business 
Institute, California State University, 
Los Angeles, USA

Prof. Dimitrios Mavrakis
Director, Energy Policy and 
Development Centre, National and 
Kapodistrian University of Athens, 
Greece

Prof. Steve McGuire
Director, Entrepreneurship Institute, 
California State University, 
Los Angeles, USA

Prof. Rustem Nureev
Head of the Department of Economic 
Theory, Financial University, 
Russia

Dr. Oleg V. Pavlov
Associate Professor of Economics and 
System Dynamics, Department of Social 
Science and Policy Studies, Worcester 
Polytechnic Institute, USA

Prof. Boris Porfi riev
Deputy Director, Institute of Economic 
Forecasting, Russian Academy of 
Sciences, Russia

Prof. Svetlozar T. Rachev
Professor of Finance, College of 
Business, Stony Brook University, USA

Prof. Boris Rubtsov
Chair of Financial Markets and 
Financial Engineering, Financial 
University, Russia

Dr. Minghao Shen
Dean, Center for Cantonese Merchants 
Research, Guangdong University of 
Foreign Studies, China

Prof. Dmitry Sorokin
Chairman for Research, Financial 
University, Russia

Prof. Robert L. Tang
Vice Chancellor for Academic, De La 
Salle College of Saint Benilde, Manila, 
The Philippines

Dr. Dimitrios Tsomocos 
Saïd Business School, Fellow in 
Management, University of Oxford; 
Senior Research Associate, Financial 
Markets Group, London School 
of Economics, UK

Prof. Sun Xiaoqin
Dean, Graduate School of Business, 
Guangdong University of Foreign 
Studies, China

REVIEW OF BUSINESS 
AND ECONOMICS STUDIES 
(ROBES) is the quarterly peerreviewed scholarly journal published 
by the Financial University under 
the Government of Russian 
Federation, Moscow. Journal’s 
mission is to provide scientifi c 
perspective on wide range of topical 
economic and business subjects.

CONTACT INFORMATION
Financial University
Leningradsky prospekt, 53, 
offi ce 5.4
123995 Moscow
Russian Federation
Telephone: +7 (499) 943-94-53
Website: www.robes.fa.ru

AUTHOR INQUIRIES
Inquiries relating to the 
submission of articles can be sent 
by electronic mail to robes@fa.ru.

COPYRIGHT AND PHOTOCOPYING 
© 2016 Review of Business and 
Economics Studies. All rights 
reserved. No part of this publication 
may be reproduced, stored 
or transmitted in any form or by any 
means without the prior permission 
in writing from the copyright holder. 
Single photocopies of articles may 
be made for personal use as allowed 
by national copyright laws. 
ISSN 2308-944X

Вестник
исследований
бизнеса 
и экономики

ГЛАВНЫЙ РЕДАКТОР
А.И. Ильинский, профессор, декан 
Международного финансо вого факультета Финансового университета 

ВЫПУСКАЮЩИЙ РЕДАКТОР
Збигнев Межва, д-р экон. наук

РЕДАКЦИОННЫЙ СОВЕТ

М.М. Алексанян, профессор Бизнесшколы им. Адама Смита, Университет 
Глазго (Великобритания)

К. Вонг, профессор, директор Института азиатско-тихоокеанского бизнеса 
Университета штата Калифорния, 
Лос-Анджелес (США)

К.П. Глущенко, профессор экономического факультета Новосибирского 
госуниверситета

С. Джеимангал, профессор Департамента статистики и математических финансов Университета Торонто 
(Канада)

Д. Дикинсон, профессор Департамента экономики Бирмингемской бизнесшколы, Бирмингемский университет 
(Великобритания)

Б. Каминский, профессор, 
Мэрилендский университет (США); 
Университет информационных 
технологий и менеджмента в Жешуве 
(Польша)

В.Л. Квинт, заведующий кафедрой 
финансовой стратегии Московской 
школы экономики МГУ, профессор 
Школы бизнеса Лассальского университета (США)

Г. Б. Клейнер, профессор, член-корреспондент РАН, заместитель директора Центрального экономико-математического института РАН

Э. Крочи, профессор, директор по 
научной работе Центра исследований 
в области энергетики и экономики 
окружающей среды Университета 
Боккони (Италия)

Д. Мавракис, профессор, 
директор Центра политики 
и развития энергетики 
Национального университета 
Афин (Греция)

С. Макгвайр, профессор, директор Института предпринимательства 
Университета штата Калифорния, 
Лос-Анджелес (США)

А. Мельников, профессор 
Депар та мента математических 
и ста тистических исследований 
Университета провинции Альберта 
(Канада)

Р.М. Нуреев, профессор, заведующий 
кафедрой «Экономическая теория» 
Финансового университета

О.В. Павлов, профессор 
Депар та мента по литологии 
и полити ческих исследований 
Ворчестерского политехнического 
института (США) 

Б.Н. Порфирьев, профессор, 
член-корреспондент РАН, заместитель директора Института 
народнохозяйственного прогнозирования РАН

С. Рачев, профессор Бизнес-колледжа Университета Стони Брук 
(США) 

Б.Б. Рубцов, профессор, заведующий 
кафедрой «Финансовые рынки и финансовый инжиниринг» Финансового университета

Д.Е. Сорокин, профессор, членкорреспондент РАН, научный 
руководитель Финансового 
университета

Р. Тан, профессор, проректор 
Колледжа Де Ла Саль Св. Бенильды 
(Филиппины) 

Д. Тсомокос, Оксфордский университет, старший научный сотрудник 
Лондонской школы экономики 
(Великобритания)

Ч.Т. Фан, профессор, Институт 
права в области науки и технологии, 
национальный университет Цин Хуа 
(Тайвань)

В. Фок, профессор, директор по 
исследованиям азиатского бизнеса Бизнес-колледжа Университета 
Лойола (США)

Д.Е. Халкос, профессор, Университет 
Фессалии (Греция)

К.А. Хартвелл, президент Центра 
социальных и экономических исследований CASE (Польша)

М. Чудри, профессор, Университет 
Брунеля (Великобритания)

Сун Цяокин, профессор, декан Высшей школы бизнеса Гуандунского 
университета зарубежных исследований (КНР)

М. Шен, декан Центра кантонских 
рыночных исследований Гуандунского университета (КНР)

Издательство Финансового 
университета
123995, Москва, ГСП-5, 
Ленинградский пр-т, 53, 
комн. 5.4
Тел. 8 (499) 943-94-53.
Интернет: www.robes.fa.ru.

Журнал "Review of Business and 
Economics Studies" («Вест ник 
исследований бизнеса и экономики») зарегистрирован 
в Федеральной службе по надзору в сфере связи, информационных технологий и массовых 
коммуникаций 9 июля 2013 г. 
Свидетельство о регистрации 
ПИ № ФС77-54658. 

Подписано в печать: 05.04.2016.
Формат 60 × 84 1/8.
Заказ № 322 от 04.04.2016. 
Отпечатано в ООП Издательства 
Финуниверситета 
(Ленинградский проспект, д. 49).
16+

CONTENTS

Secrets and perspectives of Uzbekistan’s industrial policy

Vladimir Popov . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .5

Russia: searching for friendly-oriented countries

Zbigniew Mierzwa  . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .26

How technology drove the shale oil industry 

and what it means to Russia

Art Franczek . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .63

Under which conditions can an import substitution policy 

be a driver for re-industrialisation?

Jean-Louis Truel, Yanina Pashchenko . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .68

Bounded rationality: psychological analysis of debt behaviour

Anna Smurygina, Maria Gagarina. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .75

Experiences of green credit development — 

lessons learned to Vietnam

Do Thi Van Trang . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .85

Review of the book of Alexander Melnikov 

“Risk Analysis in Finance and Insurance”

Roman Makarov . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .92

Review of 
Business and
Economics 
Studies

Volume 4, Number 1, 2016

Вестник
исследований
бизнеса 
и экономики

№ 1, 2016

CОДЕРЖАНИЕ

Секреты и перспективы промышленной 

политики Узбекистана

Владимир Попов . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .5

Россия в поисках дружественно ориентированных стран

Збигнев Межва . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .26

Как технологии стимулируют сланцевую

индустрию и какое это имеет значение для России

Арт Франчек . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .63

При каких условиях политика импортозамещения 

может стимулировать реиндустриализацию

Жан-Луис Трюэль, Янина Пащенко . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .68

Ограниченная рациональность: 

психологический анализ поведения должников

Анна Смурыгина, Мария Гагарина . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .75

Опыт развития «зеленого» кредитования: 

уроки важные для Вьетнама

До Тхи Ван Транг  . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .85

Обзор книги Александра Мельникова 

«Риск-анализ в финансах и страховании»

Роман Макаров . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .92

Review of Business and Economics Studies  
 
Volume 4, Number 1, 2016

I. INTRODUCTION
Uzbekistan in the past 10 years has been a successful economy. It attained high growth (8%), 
low unemployment, reasonable macro-econom
ic stability, low domestic and international debt 
and relatively low inequality. Of note are the 
structural shifts, which occurred in the recent 
25 years post-independence:

What can Uzbekistan tell us about industrial 
policy that we did not already know

Vladimir Popov, 
Ph.D. in economics, professor, CEMI RAN (Central Economics and Mathematics Institute of the Russian 
Academy of Sciences), Laboratory of Mathematical Economics, Institute of European and Russian Studies 
at Carleton University in Ottawa
popovv@vn.org

Abstract. This paper discusses Uzbekistan’s recent experience with structural shifts and industrial 
policy and the larger implications for existing theories of industrial policy. The paper has a particular 
focus on various industry policy instruments. Two major hypotheses are discussed: (1) the hypothesis 
of Haussmann, Hwang and Rodrik (the more technologically sophisticated the export structure, the 
better for growth) and (2) the hypothesis of Justin Yifu Lin (export specialization should build on 
existing comparative advantages and not jump over the necessary technological stages).

Keywords: Uzbekistan, economic growth, economic diversifi cation, industrial policy, exchange rate 
policy, wages policy.

Секреты и перспективы 
промышленной политики Узбекистана

Владимир Попов,
д-р экон. наук, профессор, ЦЭМИ РАН, Институт исследований Европы, 
России и Евразии Карлтонского университета (Оттава)

Аннотация. В статье обсуждается опыт Узбекистана в области структурных преобразований 
и промышленной политики, а также важные последствия для существующих теорий 
промышленной политики. Проверены две основные гипотезы: гипотеза Хауссмана, Хванга 
и Родрика (чем более технологически диверсифицирована структура экспорта, тем лучше 
экономический рост) и гипотеза Джастина Ыифу Лин (экспортная специализация должна строиться 
на существующих сравнительных преимуществах и не перешагивать через необходимые 
технологические стадии). Узбекистан, создавший автомобильную промышленность с нуля, 
сегодня производит более 200 тыс. автомобилей в год, половина из которых экспортируется. 
Это, несомненно, успех промышленной политики. Вместе с тем ставка на развитие тяжелой химии 
может привести к замедлению экономического роста страны.

Ключевые слова: Узбекистан, экономический рост, экономическая диверсификация, промышленная 
политика, политика валютного курса, политика заработной платы.

JEL classifi cation: O14, O25, O4, O53

Review of Business and Economics Studies  
 
Volume 4, Number 1, 2016

(1) A decrease in the production and export of 
cotton (previously a mono-culture), an increase 
in food production and the attainment of food 
self-suffi ciency.
(2) An attainment of country’s energy selfsuffi ciency.
(3) An increase in the share of industry in 
GDP and the share of machinery and equipment 
production in industrial output, and export as 
well. Point in case, a competitive export oriented 
auto industry was created from the ground up. In 
addition, in recent years, Uzbekistan promoted 
heavy chemical industries such as the production of synthetic fuel and polypropylene goods 
from natural gas.
This paper argues that Uzbekistan’s achievements in development have been due to deliberate government policies rather than simply the 
result of economic liberalization reforms to conform to its factor endowment and/or the result of 
a natural comparative advantage. The paper acknowledges Uzbekistan’s enjoyment of a favourable external environment; however, it attributes 
its rapid growth to reasonable macroeconomic 
stability and industrial policies. It begins with a 
brief discussion of industry policy and economic 
diversifi cation in the post-Soviet States in Central 
Asia and Eastern Europe including Russia. The 
rest of the paper is organized as follows:
• Section III compares Uzbekistan’s transition and economic performance vis-à-vis other 
post-Soviet States;
• Section IV discusses changes in the economic structure of Uzbekistan;
• Section V shows that the main instrument 
of Uzbekistan’s industrial policy has been the 
under-valuation of the exchange rate;
• Section VI reflects on the issues of industrial upgrading — the dilemma of choosing “winning” industries in the context of the 
general debate about the nature of industrial 
policy, especially the hypothesis advanced by 
Haussmann, Hwang and Rodrik vis-à-vis that 
by Justin Yifu Lin;
• Section VII contains concluding remarks 
on the lessons learned from Uzbekistan’s industrial policies and the lessons which Uzbekistan can benefi t from vis-à-vis the experiences 
of successful East Asian countries, especially 
Singapore, in the attempt to upgrade industrial 
structures.

II. INDUSTRIAL POLICY 
AND ECONOMIC DIVERSIFICATION
Industrial structure is important for economic development. The Chenery (1960) hypothesis states 
that countries at similar levels of economic development should have similar patterns of resource 
allocation between sectors. But in theoretical models it is often assumed that there are externalities 
from industrialization and industrial export (Murphy, Shleifer & Vishny, 1989; Polterovich & Popov, 
2004, 2005). There is growing evidence that countries which are more industrialized and countries 
with more technologically sophisticated industrial 
export are growing faster than others (Hausmann, 
Hwang & Rodrik, 2006; Rodrik, 2006).
Not all countries are able to climb the technological ladder, diversify, and upgrade the 
structure of their economy and export. In most 
transition economies a “primitivization” of the 
industrial structure occurred. In other words, 
secondary manufacturing and high tech industries proved to be uncompetitive and their output was curtailed after the deregulation of prices 
and the opening of the economy. As a matter of 
fact, an increase in the share of the service sector, especially trade and fi nance, at the expense 
of industry (deindustrialization) occurred in all 
post-communist economies. Previously in the 
centrally planned economies the service sector, 
in particular trade and fi nance, were underdeveloped. It seems, however, that in many of these 
economies deindustrialization went too far. In 
Tajikistan, for example, the share of services in 
GDP nearly doubled, increasing from about 30% 
in the early 1990s to 57% in 2010, whereas the 
share of manufacturing in GDP fell from 25% in 
1990 to 10% in 2010. In Russia the share of industry in GDP fell from about 1/2 in 1990 to 
about 1/3 in the mid 1990s, whereas within industry itself the share of the primary sector (fuel, 
energy, steel and non-ferrous metals) in the total 
industrial output increased from 25% to over 50%.
The structure of exports in most post-Soviet 
states also became more primitive in the recent 
two decades; the share of manufactured goods in 
total exports either declined or did not show any 
clear tendency towards increase (Figure 1). This 
was partly caused by the increase in resource price 
and resource boom: expansion of fuel production 
and exports in Azerbaijan, Kazakhstan, Russia, and 
Turkmenistan. In Russia the share of fuel, min
Review of Business and Economics Studies  
 
Volume 4, Number 1, 2016

erals, metals and diamonds in total export grew 
from 52% in 1990 (USSR) to 67% in 1995 and 81% 
in 2012. In contrast, the share of machinery and 
equipment in total export fell from 18% in 1990 
(USSR) to 10% in 1995 and 4.5% in 2012.
Such changes in the industrial structure 
were not solely the result of an “invisible hand 
of the market”. Greenwald and Stiglitz (1986, 
2013) state: market failures are pervasive, private rewards and social rewards virtually always differ. Governments, then, are inevitably 
involved in shaping the industrial structure 
of the economy, both by what they do and do 
not do. As many authors point out, the secret 
of “good” industrial policy in East Asia, as opposed to “bad” industrial policy in the former 
Soviet Union, Latin America and Africa may be 
associated with the ability to reap the benefits 
of export externalities (Khan, 2007a; Gibbs, 
2007). Exporting to world markets, especially 
to developed countries, enables the upgrade 
of quality and technology standards and 
yields social returns in excess of the returns 
to particular exporters. The greatest increases 
in productivity are registered at companies 
that export to advanced (Western) markets 
and which export hi-tech goods (Harris & Li, 
2007; Shevtsova, 2012). In addition, it has been 
shown that the gap between the actual level of 
development and the hypothetical level, which 
corresponds to the degree of sophistication of 

a country’s exports, is strongly correlated with 
productivity growth rates (Hausmann et al., 
2006). In other words, it pays off to promote 
exports of sophisticated and high tech goods. 
Not all countries which attempt to promote 
such exports succeed, but those that do not try, 
virtually never engineer growth miracles1.
It is worth noting that there is an opposite 
view as demonstrated, for example, in a recent 
paper from the World Bank (Gill, et al, 2014). 
The paper concludes that it is not clear whether 
diversifying exports and production is necessary for development and that governments 
need concern themselves less with the composition of exports, profile of production and 
more with their national asset portfolios — the 
natural resources, built capital, and economic 
institutions.

III. UZBEKISTAN’S TRANSITION 
AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
After the collapse of the USSR and the market oriented reforms in successor states the comparative 
performance in the post-Soviet space varied greatly 
(Figure 2). In retrospect, it is clear that rapid economic liberalization did not pay off: many gradual 
reformers (labelled procrastinators at the time) 

1 Botswana may be the only exception as it has one of the highest rates of per-capita GDP growth in the last 50 years (5% 
during 1960–2010), which was primarily driven by exports of 
primary commodities (namely, diamonds) and not of high-tech 
goods.

Figure 1. Manufactures exports, % of merchandise export

Source: WDI.

Review of Business and Economics Studies  
 
Volume 4, Number 1, 2016

from the former Soviet Union (FSU) performed 
better than champions of big-bang liberalization 
(Baltic States and Central Europe). In Belarus, 
Turkmenistan and Uzbekistan, for instance, privatization was slow; over 50% of GDP is created in 
state enterprise (Figure 3), yet their performance 
is superior to that of more liberalized economies. 
Recently when resource prices were high, resource 
abundance helped exporters such as Azerbaijan, 
Kazakhstan, Russia and Turkmenistan, to maintain higher income. However, this was not a sine 
qua non for growth; resource poor Belarus and selfsuffi cient in fuel and energy Uzbekistan did much 
better than resource rich Russia.
As recent research shows, the crucial factor in 
economic performance is the ability to preserve 
the institutional capacity of the state (Popov, 
2007, 2011 for a survey). The story of transition 
was very much a government capability, rather 

than a market failure. In all former Soviet republics and in the East European countries, government spending fell during transition and the provision of traditional public goods, from law and 
order to health care and infrastructure, worsened. 
This led to an increase in income inequalities, 
shadow economy, corruption, crime and mortality2. But in countries with the smallest decline in 

2 State capacity is understood as the ability of the state to enforce rules and regulations and is measured by objective indicators such as crime rate, murder rate, the share of shadow economy, i. e. the degree of compliance with tax rules and criminal 
code (the murder rate is better than the crime rate due to statistical registration problems, see Popov, 2008).
There are well known problems with subjective measures of 
institutional capacity, such as corruption perception indices 
of Transparency International and the World Bank indices of 
government effectiveness, rule of law, etc. (Khan, 2007b; Popov, 
2011). The institutional capacity declined dramatically in the 
1990s in many transition economies; all three traditional monopolies of the state (on violence, tax collection and issuance 
of currency) were undermined (Popov, 2004).

Figure 2. GDP change in FSU economies, 1989 = 100%

Source: EBRD Transition Reports for various years. Central Europe is the unweighted average for Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland, 
Slovakia and Slovenia.

Review of Business and Economics Studies  
 
Volume 4, Number 1, 2016

government spending (countries which are diverse in other respects — Central Europe, Estonia, 
Belarus, Uzbekistan), these effects were less pronounced and the dynamics of output was better.
Uzbekistan is an economic success story in 
the post-Soviet space. Its transformation-stage 
recession was very mild as compared to other 
countries of the former Soviet Union: its GDP 
more than doubled in 1989–2012, a better result than even in Central European countries 
(Figure 2). Its life expectancy, currently at 68 
years, may have not increased much, but it did 
not fall as it did in other former Soviet republics in the 1990s. Its population increased from 
20 million in 1989 to 30 million in 2013; and its 
murder rate is low (3 per 100, 000 of inhabitants, 
a fi gure lower than in the US). In 2009 during the 
economic recession, only Kazakhstan and Azerbaijan showed higher economic growth rates 
than that of Uzbekistan, whereas most postcommunist countries experienced a reduction of 
output.
Uzbekistan’s performance is not as spectacular as that of China; nevertheless, it is exceptional 
for the post-Soviet space. This is partly due to a 
good external environment; Uzbekistan exports 

the commodities cotton, gold and gas, which have 
experienced an international increase in prices 
in the past 2 decades. However, reasons that are 
more important are attributed to the good macroeconomic and industrial policies. Uzbekistan 
is the only country in the post-Soviet space that 
succeeded in increasing the share of industry in 
GDP and the share of machinery and equipment 
in the total industrial output, and export. It created a competitive export-oriented auto industry 
from the ground up. In 2011, it became the 15th 
country in the world to launch a high-speed train 
line (between Tashkent and Samarkand to be extended to Bukhara and Karshi by 2015). The train 
is made by the Spanish Talgo and runs a distance 
of 344 km in 2 hours, 8 minutes.
The inclusiveness of growth appears to be 
higher in Uzbekistan as well. In 2012, Uzbekistan’s offi cial estimates for the Gini coeffi cient 
was just above 30% (World Bank estimates for 
2002–03 is 35–36%). This is lower than in most 
transition economies. Meanwhile, in the more 
liberalized economies of Russia, Lithuania, 
Georgia and Kyrgyzstan income distribution is 
noticeably more uneven, ranging between 0.38 
and 0.45 (Appendix Figure A1).

Figure 3. The share of private sector in GDP in some former Soviet republics, 1989–2009, %

Source: EBRD.

Review of Business and Economics Studies  
 
Volume 4, Number 1, 2016

Another indicator of income distribution is 
the number of billionaires3. The 2013 Forbes 
count placed Russia and Georgia ahead in billionaire-intensity (number of billionaires per $ 1 
trillion PPP GDP), followed by Ukraine, Czech 
Republic and Kazakhstan (Table 1). Other former USSR countries do not have billionaires yet, 
although their PPP GDP is higher than that of 
Georgia. For example, Azerbaijan and Uzbekistan are supposed to have about 3 billionaires 
had they the same level of billionaire-intensity 
as Russia. However, in fact, they do not.
The relatively successful economic performance is even more impressive given that Uzbekistan is not a major oil and gas exporter and 

3 The statistics on the number of billionaires published by 
Forbes annually allegedly characterize income distribution at 
the very top of the wealth pyramid. The number of billionaires 
depends mostly on the total size of the country’s GDP. Much less 
important is the per capita GDP. The relationship is non-linear:
Number of billionaires in 2007 = –0.9 + 0.367y – 0.0049y2 +
+ 2.6Y2, where
y — PPP GDP per capita in thousand $ in 2005, 
Y — PPP GDP in 2005 in trillions.
N = 181, R2 = 0.95, all coeffi cients signifi cant at 1% level.
Countries which exceed the predicted number of billionaires 
considerably (2 times and more) are: Canada, Israel, Germany, Spain, UK, India, Turkey, Saudi Arabia, Egypt, Hong Kong, 
Malaysia, Philippines, Brazil, Russia, Ukraine, Kazakhstan. In 
contrast, countries where the number of billionaires is considerably lower than predicted are Japan, China, most countries of 
Western Europe, Oman, Argentina, Romania, Czech Republic 
(Popov, 2014c).

that it is one of two (the other being Liechtenstein) double landlocked countries4 in the world. 
It is important, however, to distinguish between 
growth rates and the level of per capita income. Uzbekistan remains a poor country with 
PPP GDP per capita of below $US 6000 in 2014 
against over $ 20,000 in Russia and Kazakhstan, 
$ 17,000 in Azerbaijan and over $ 14,000 in Turkmenistan. Many Uzbeks are migrating to find 
jobs in Russia. The reverse is not true.
It is necessary to separate the effects associated with the dynamics of output from the effects of the terms of trade and fi nancial fl ows. 
At the end of the Soviet period, in the 1980s, 
real incomes in Uzbekistan were about half of 
those in Russia. After the collapse of the USSR, 
real incomes in non-resource republics fell dramatically due to the change in relative prices; 
oil, gas and other resources became several 
times more expensive relative to ready-made 
goods. Uzbekistan was a large importer of oil 
and its trade with all countries, including other 
Soviet republics, if recalculated in world prices, 
yielded a defi cit of 9% of GDP (Soviet economy, 
1990). To make matters worse, the collapse of 
the Soviet Union dried up fi nancial fl ows from 
Moscow. In 1990, inter-budgetary transfers 

4 Double landlocked countries are countries fully surrounded 
by other landlocked countries.

Table 1. Billionaires in former USSR, Eastern Europe China and Vietnam

Number of 
billionaires
Total 
wealth
PPP GDP, 
2012
Number per 1 
trillion PPP GDP
Wealth of billionaires 
to PPP GDP, %

China
122
260.9
12471
9.8
2.1

Russia
110
403.8
3380
32.5
11.9

Ukraine
10
31.3
338.2
29.6
9.3

Kazakhstan
5
9.2
233
21.5
3.9

Czech 
Republic
4
14.0
277.9
14.4
5.0

Poland
4
9.8
844.2
4.7
1.2

Georgia
1
5.3
26.6
37.6
19.9

Vietnam
1
1.5
322.7
3.1
0.5

Romania
1
1.1
352.3
2.8
0.3

Uzbekistan
0
0
107
0.0
0.0

Source: Forbes billionaires list.
(http://www.forbes.com/billionaires/#page: 1_sort: 0_direction: asc_search: _fi lter: All%20industries_fi lter: All%20countries_fi lter: 
All%20states); WDI.

Review of Business and Economics Studies  
 
Volume 4, Number 1, 2016

from the Union budget amounted to 31% of 
the revenues of the republican budget (Soviet 
Economy, 1991).
Hence, the sharp reduction of real incomes in 
the early 1990s was larger than the reduction of 
output and was primarily due to a poor external 
environment and circumstance, rather than policy and choice. However, the dynamics of real output, i. e. the physical volume of output (Figure 1) 
which is dependent on circumstances and policy, was better than in all countries of Eastern 
Europe and former USSR with the exception of 
Turkmenistan.

IV. CHANGES IN UZBEKISTAN’S 
ECONOMIC STRUCTURE
Since the 1991 independence, Uzbekistan encouraged and carried out three important structural shifts in its economy: (1) a decrease in cotton production and export and an increase in 
food production, achieving food self-suffi ciency, 
(2) an attainment of energy self-suffi ciency and 
an achievement of net fuel export, (3) an increase in the share of industry in GDP and the 
share of machinery and equipment in industrial 
output, export.
Diversification in agriculture was carried 
out mostly via state orders: less for cotton, 
more for cereals. Thus, the production of cotton decreased by 50%as compared to the late 

1980s, and the output of cereals and vegetables 
increased several folds (Figure 4). The increase 
in gas output was due mostly to state investments: gas and oil are produced by the state 
holding company “Uzbekneftegaz”. The diversifi cation in industry and the expansion of 
manufacturing exports was mostly the result of 
protectionism and of the policy of low exchange 
rate by the government / central bank. Like China, Uzbekistan maintained a low (undervalued) 
exchange rate due to rapid accumulation of foreign exchange reserves. In addition, there were 
non-negligible tax measures to stimulate the 
export of processed goods (50% lower tax rates 
for manufacturing companies that export 30% 
and more of their output).
Although comparable statistics from WDI for 
Uzbekistan is lacking, national statistics suggests that the share of non-resource goods in 
exports increased to over 70% against less than 
30% in 1990, before independence (Foreign Affairs Department of Uzbekistan, 2013).
Uzbekistan is one of the few transition 
countries where the share of industry increased in recent years (Figure 5). It also was 
able to upgrade its structure of industrial output; the share of machinery, equipment and 
chemicals increased at the expense of light 
industry (Table 2). Other post-Soviet economies also experienced the decline of light in
Figure 4. Diversifi cation in agriculture

Source: State Committee on Statistics of Uzbekistan (http://www.stat.uz/en/).

Review of Business and Economics Studies  
 
Volume 4, Number 1, 2016

dustry, but it happened together with the decline of machine building that created space 
for the expansion of fuel, energy, steel and 
non-ferrous metals. During the Soviet era, in a 
centrally planned economy, resource rent was 
removed from resource industries and given 
to secondary manufacturing through the pricing mechanism; prices for commodities and 
low processed goods were set at levels below 
the world marker, whereas prices for finished 
goods were established at an artificially high 
level. Once prices were allowed to be determined by the market after the deregulation 
in 1992, they got closer to the world levels 
and terms of trade for resource industries 
improved, but deteriorated for the secondary 
manufacturing.
After independence, an automobile industry 
was created in Uzbekistan from the ground up. 
Car production was supported by the government and the Korean auto company Daewoo. 
After Daewoo declared bankruptcy, US General 
Motors became the government’s partner. The 
government also bought a stake in Turkey’s 

Koc in SamKochAvto, a producer of small buses 
and lorries. Afterwards, it signed an agreement 
with Isuzu Motors of Japan to produce Isuzu 
buses and lorries. In 2014 Uzbekistan produced 
250,000 cars and nearly a quarter were exported5. 
In 2011 a joint venture of State Auto Company 
and General Motors, the engine plant in Tashkent, became operational with a capacity of 
360,000 engines a year.
Uzbekistan’s exports increased dramatically: 
from $ 2 billion in 1992 to $ 15 billion in 2011, 
or from $ 100 to $ 500 per capita (Figure 6). The 
share of former USSR countries in exports fell 
from over 60% in 1992 to less than 40% in 2012 
(Appendix Figure A2). The share of cotton in export fell from 65% in 1992 to only 9% in 2012. 
The share of fuel (mostly gas) and oil products 

5 In 2013 Uzbekistan sold over 60,000 cars to Russia and 33,000 
to Kazakhstan. In 2014–15 export fell dramatically due to a 
recession in Russia. In 2014 car output was 246,000 including 
over 55,000 for export (38,000 to Russia, the rest to Kazakhstan, Azerbaijan, Ukraine, Belarus and also to Indonesia, Brazil, 
Turkey, South Korea). The share of joint venture company “GM 
Uzbekistan” in the Russian car market fell to 1.5% in 2014 from 
2.2% in 2013 (UzDaily.uz, 2015 — http://www.uzdaily.uz).

Figure 5. GDP structure by sectors of the economy, % of total

Source: WB, 2013.